PERSPECTIVE
  • Home
  • About
  • Contact
  • Blog
  • Home
  • About
  • Contact
  • Blog

OUR VIEW

The secret life of the LRF

28/4/2017

1 Comment

 
Minimising the risk of a CSCF in ETS Phase IV has preoccupied policymakers, but the choice to apply the LRF to certain allocations has slipped under the radar unquestioned.

​The Linear Reduction Factor (LRF) is not just used to calculate the number of ETS allowances issued each year. It's also used to reduce free allocation to certain installations in much the same way as the more notorious Cross-Sectoral Correction Factor (CSCF). This has not received the attention it deserves and could have significant implications in Phase IV for new and expanding installations.

According to Article 10a (paragraphs 4 and 7) of the EU ETS Directive (and the related Benchmarking Decision), the LRF must be applied when calculating allocation to certain installations that generate electricity, as well as new capacity entering the EU ETS. This is done cumulatively, cutting allocation by an additional 1.74% every year during Phase III. Other installations receiving free allocation, meanwhile, have the CSCF applied instead (if there is one).

In Phase III, installations subject to the LRF will lose a smaller proportion of their allocation than those exposed to the CSCF: 12.2% in 2020, for example, rather than 17.5% (based on the original CSCF values). But in Phase IV the situation may well be reversed, as the LRF increases and measures to reduce the risk of a CSCF (such as auction share flexibility) are introduced.

If the LRF haircut were reset to 0% at the beginning of Phase IV and then raised annually by 2.2 percentage points, installations exposed to the LRF would lose 19.8% of their entitlement in 2030 and almost 10% on average during the phase. This exceeds most expectations for a Phase IV CSCF. If, on the other hand, the LRF haircut was not reset but continued from where it left off in Phase III, it would cut relevant entitlements by 14.4% in 2021 and 34.2% in 2030, averaging 24.3% across the phase. This far exceeds forecasts for the CSCF. 

If the LRF continues to be applied to new entrants' and expanding incumbents' allocations in Phase IV, then, it could mean that new production receives significantly fewer allowances than incumbent production (until accommodated in the next NIMs round), even if it is indistinguishable in every respect and the New Entrants' Reserve is well stocked.

We might question why the LRF is being applied at all. The CSCF is triggered by a shortfall in allowances that year, but applying the LRF is a choice with no direct connection to constraint in supply. If policymakers are determined to eliminate the CSCF, why are they choosing to apply the LRF?

Perhaps the argument will be made that installations should be improving their emissions intensity in line with the ETS cap so should receive fewer allowances every year. But the new benchmark proposals for Phase IV already factor in annual improvements in a more nuanced way. And this wouldn't justify applying the LRF selectively to new production, creating an uneven playing field between installations. Or perhaps the aim is to level the playing field with incumbent installations subject to the CSCF. But in this case why not apply the CSCF to new production rather than a different haircut?

For many installations, the LRF could be the threat in Phase IV, not the CSCF. This could be changed by policymakers at the stroke of a pen, without the need for complex mechanisms, and deserves greater attention during trilogue. If, the ETS Directive retains provisions in this area, it will be important to define in implementing legislation how the LRF will be baselined and whether it will apply to expanding installations' as well as new entrants' allocations.

Contact:

damien.green@perspectiveclimate.com
1 Comment

Understanding the Council's MSR proposals

8/3/2017

1 Comment

 
The Council's MSR proposals could cancel 2-3 billion ETS allowances in Phase IV (2021-30)

The Council has proposed doubling the withdrawal rate of the MSR for 5 years, and cancelling MSR allowances from 2024 when the number exceeds the amount auctioned the previous year.

Parliament by comparison has proposed doubling the MSR rate for ~4 years, and cancelling 800 million allowances ahead of Phase IV.

Our provisional modelling suggests that the Council position would cancel far more allowances, perhaps 2-3 billion, with the vast majority being cancelled in 2024.

We estimate, for instance, that 2.7 billion allowances would be cancelled during Phase IV, with 2.1 billion being cancelled in 2024, making the following assumptions:

  • Emissions run 5% below the Phase IV cap
  • The auction share is 55% each year (i.e. the Council's proposed 2% flexibility is used)
  • Surplus allowances enter the MSR at an annual rate of 24% until 2024 and 12% afterwards, unless the market surplus is below 833 million
  • Allowances are cancelled from 2024 when the number exceeds the amount auctioned the previous year
Picture
If emissions run further below the cap, we would expect greater cancellation. Bearing in mind this sensitivity, we estimate that cancellation would fall in the range of 2-3 billion, with around 2 billion cancelled in 2024.

Contact:

damien.green@perspectiveclimate.com
1 Comment

Council agrees ETS General Approach

8/3/2017

1 Comment

 
On 28th February the EU Council adopted a General Approach on ETS reform that will form the basis of its negotiating position in trilogue.
 
It’s structured on the Commission's 2015 proposal, but with significant strengthening of the Market Stability Reserve (MSR), more accurate benchmark reductions, and 2% flexibility in the auction share.
 
Surprisingly, the position is more ambitious than Parliament’s adopted on 15th February, and provides industry with less protection from a correction factor (i.e. it carries a higher risk of a haircut in free allocation).
 
We now have a good sense of each institution’s position, and it is evident that there is a great deal of convergence. We can predict with some confidence, then, that the final ETS reform package will look roughly as follows:

  • 2.2% Linear Reduction Factor (2021-30)
  • 57% auction share with 2-5% flexibility to protect against a CSCF (2021-30)
  • 24% MSR withdrawal rate for 4-5 years from 2019
  • Significant cancellation of MSR allowances (from 800 million to perhaps 3 billion, either before or during Phase IV)
  • Benchmark reductions in 2021 and 2026 based on the measured improvement of the top 10% (within a corridor of around 0.25% -1.5% per annum from 2008, defined with respect to 2023 and 2028 respectively)
  • Adjustments to free allocation based on production changes administered in 10-15% increments (2021-30)
 
How the institutions compromise on MSR cancellation and auction share flexibility will be the most critical areas to watch during trilogue, in terms of the impact on carbon prices and the risk of a Phase IV correction factor.
 
Other areas to watch (where there is less agreement) include, how funds are stocked (which has an impact on the correction factor), and whether there is central compensation for indirect carbon costs (as proposed by Parliament but not Council). 
 
Contact:

damien.green@perspectiveclimate.com
​
Notes:
 
The main aspects of the Council’s position are as follows:

  • The Phase IV cap would be reduced by a Linear Reduction Factor of 2.2% (i.e. 48,380,081 fewer allowances would be issued each year between 2021-30 if the reference cap for the LRF were unchanged).
  • 57% of allowances issued each year would belong to the auction share, and 43% to the free share
  • A number of allowances equivalent to 2% of the total issued during the Phase could be transferred from the auction share to the free share when there would otherwise be too few to honour free allocation commitments to installations
  • The withdrawal rate of the Market Stability Reserve (MSR) would be doubled for five years (2019-24), withdrawing 24% of surplus allowances each year (when the surplus exceeds a certain threshold—originally intended to be 833 million)
  • MSR allowances would be cancelled annually from 2024 when the number exceeds the amount of allowances auctioned the previous year 
  • Benchmarks would be reduced in 2021 and 2026 based on the measured improvement of the top 10% (within a corridor of 0.2% - 1.5% per annum from 2008, defined with respect to 2023 and 2028 respectively)
  • Free allocation would be adjusted when activity increases/decreases in 15% increments compared to levels recorded under Article 11
  • Member States could provide indirect cost compensation (within State Aid rules), but they would be encouraged not to use more than 25% of auction revenues for this purpose 
  • Funds would be stocked as in the Commission’s 2015 proposal:
    • The Modernisation Fund would be supplied from the auction share (with a number equivalent to 2% of total allowances)
    • The Innovation Fund would comprise 400 million allowances from the free share and 50 million from the MSR
    • The New Entrants' Reserve would be stocked with 250 million allowances from the MSR and 145 million allowances that weren't allocated to non-carbon-leakage sectors during Phase III, as well as allowances freed up during Phase IV due to significant reductions in production compared to levels assumed in entitlements
1 Comment

Will the CSCF return in EU ETS Phase IV?

18/2/2017

0 Comments

 
 If the 'Duncan mechanism' doesn't survive trilogue it could mean another CSCF in ETS Phase IV

This week the European Parliament adopted a position on EU ETS Phase IV (2021-30) that will form the basis of its negotiations with the Council and Commission in trilogue. One distinctive aspect of the position is the so-called 'Duncan mechanism', named after the file's rapporteur--Ian Duncan MEP. This would allow up to 5% of the total number of allowances to be transferred from the auction share to the free share during Phase IV if the number owed to installations would otherwise exceed the number available.

Due to the Duncan mechanism (and factoring in differences in how funds would be stocked), Parliament's proposal would make ~10% more free allowances available compared to the Commission's proposal, providing additional protection from a CSCF of ~9%. The mechanism is especially important now that other proposals that would have reduced the risk of a cross-sectoral correction factor (CSCF) have fallen by the wayside, such as tiering the carbon leakage list, and introducing carbon border adjustments for the cement sector.

Based on the emerging position in the EU Council, however, it looks like the mechanism may not survive the legislative process—at least not without significant dilution. While Member States regularly pay lip service to wanting to avoid a CSCF, the Duncan mechanism is a hard sell in the Council because governments value auction revenues, and certain Member States use a share of their auction volumes for free allocation to the power sector under Article 10c.
 
At December’s Environment Council, only a small minority of Member States expressed support for the Duncan mechanism (or expanding the size of the free share): most notably, Germany, Belgium, Italy, and Greece. Meanwhile, there was a broad group (comprising Member States that would often occupy opposing poles in the debate), expressing a preference for the Commission’s proposed auction share.
 
While all attention was focused on Parliament last week, Coreper was meeting behind closed doors, and on Friday a draft text was published with the aim of agreeing a general Council position when ministers meet on 28th February. Looking through the draft text, it’s evident that the Council’s emerging position is based closely on the Commission’s 2015 proposal, but with some important changes: namely, 1) doubling the withdrawal rate of the MSR (as proposed by Parliament), 2) reducing benchmarks more accurately (in a very similar manner to that advocated by Parliament), and 3) introducing 1% flexibility in the auction share.
 
Doubling the MSR withdrawal rate is contentious with Eastern European Member States, and the proposed 1% flexibility is a thorny issue with many, with the number still bracketed in the text. Nevertheless, we might expect the Council’s eventual adopted position (whether it's reached in February or June)—and indeed the final package to emerge from trilogue—to look quite a lot like this.
 
In terms of what this would mean for a CSCF in Phase IV, we can refer to analysts' existing models of the Commission's proposal (given the identical provisions relating to the number and distribution of allowances), and just adjust for the new aspects of this hypothetical final package. 

In terms of these adjustments, the MSR doubling proposal would not affect the CSCF estimates, because it reduces the historic market surplus via the auction share. (Although it would increase the value of any shortfall in allocation.) Having 1% flexibility in the auction share, on the other hand, would reduce the risk of a CSCF compared to the Commission's proposal, but would only provide protection from a ~2.5% haircut--significantly less than Parliament's proposal. Meanwhile, more accurate benchmark reductions (within a corridor of 0.3% - 1.5% p.a. from 2008) might be expected to result in a lower average benchmark reduction than the Commission's flat-rate proposal, which would increase the risk of a CSCF.

Making these adjustments, and assuming some modest growth, we might expect the package to trigger a CSCF if the weighted average benchmark reduction comes out below ~0.9% per annum, reaching significant levels as the reduction approaches 0.5%.

For further information, please contact damien.green@perspectiveclimate.com
0 Comments

Commission introduces stricter ETS Correction Factor

30/1/2017

1 Comment

 
UPDATED: 07/02/17

DISCLAIMER: The below represents the author's interpretation of the implications of the new CSCF, and should not be taken for the official position of the Commission.


Following a ruling from the European Court of Justice (ECJ), the European Commission has revised the Cross-Sectoral Correction Factor (CSCF) values for ETS Phase III (2013-20).
 
The new values will only be applied from March 2017 when agreeing free allocation adjustments for sites that have undergone a significant capacity reduction. When applied they will reduce free allocation to an installation by an additional 4-5 percentage points compared to the old CSCF values.

If installations require no adjustment to their free allocation (because they have not experienced a significant capacity or activity level change) their allocation up to 2020 will remain as defined in existing National Implementation Measures.

If installations require an adjustment in free allocation due to a capacity extension or change in activity level they will also be unaffected by the new values.

With capacity extensions, the additional allowances come from the New Entrants’ Reserve (NER) rather than the general pool of free allowances, and the NER is not subject to the CSCF.

And with activity level changes, Article 23 of the Benchmarking Decision is clear that an adjustment is made without a recalculation that would involve the re-application of the CSCF.

I understand that the Commission is updating its Guidance Note on free allocation adjustments to make clear that activity level changes are not affected. The note currently proposes a methodology for recalculating allocation in the instance of an activity level change that uses the CSCF, but this does not have the same legal standing as the Benchmarking Decision.

In 2013, 32 installations out of 11,000 had adjustments made to their allocation as a result of a capacity reduction. Assuming a similar proportion (~0.3%) require adjustments each year from 2017, we may see 1-1.5% of installations end up on the stricter CSCF by the end of Phase III.
 
The Commission’s interpretation of the ECJ ruling is more generous to industry than analysts had predicted, only applying the higher CSCF values from 2017 (rather than retrospectively) and then only when modifications are made due to capacity reductions.
 
The new values:
​
Picture

​The old values:
Picture

​Notes:

  • The European Court of Justice ruled on 28th April 2016 that the Commission had underestimated the Cross-Sectoral Correction Factor (CSCF) values for Phase III due to a calculating error, and instructed the Commission to revise them.
  • The CSCF is the factor by which the number of free allowances owed to installations in a given year must be multiplied so as not to exceed the amount available that year. For example, if 100 allowances were owed, but only 80 were available, a CSCF of 0.8 (or 80%) would be applied.
  • Free allocation to installations (other than ‘electricity generators’) that comes from the general free share is subject to the CSCF when there is a shortfall as described above.
  • The CSCF is often stated as a percentage haircut, so a correction factor of 0.8 might be referred to as a 20% CSCF. In this sense the new CSCF values are higher, i.e. they will reduce allocations by a larger amount.
  • When an installation undergoes a significant capacity or activity level change, the relevant Member State must agree a new allocation for the following year with the Commission.
  • From March 2017, when a new allocation is agreed with the Commission due to a capacity reduction the new CSCF values will be used.
  • Adjustments to allocations made from March to accommodate capacity extensions are not affected, however, because these allowances come from the New Entrants’ Reserve (NER).
  • The NER is formed from 5% of Phase III allowances (minus 300 million put into a fund called NER 300); it is separate from the general free share of allowances and not subject to the CSCF.
  • The NER is first come first served, but it is over 75% full according to the latest status report and is unlikely to run out by the end of the Phase.
  • When calculating allocation from the NER, the Commission applies the Linear Reduction Factor rather than the CSCF.
  • Adjustments due to an activity level change (due to partial cessation or recovery) will also unaffected by the new values. While this allocation comes from the general free share (so is subject to the CSCF), adjustments are made without re-applying the CSCF, as provided for in Article 23 of the Benchmarking Decision.
  • A ‘significant’ capacity reduction is essentially a reduction of at least 10% of initial capacity.
  • Activity levels are deemed to change when production crosses thresholds set at 50%, 25% and 10% of historic production levels.
 
Links:
 
ECJ Ruling
 
CSCF Decision
 
FAQ
 
Benchmarking Decision

Free Allocation Guidance—To Be Updated
 
2017 NER Status Report
 
2014 Activity and Capacity Changes Report
 
Contact:
 
damien.green@perspectiveclimate.com

1 Comment
Forward>>

    Damien Green

    Managing Director

    Archives

    July 2021
    March 2020
    February 2020
    July 2019
    January 2018
    December 2017
    November 2017
    June 2017
    April 2017
    March 2017
    February 2017
    January 2017

    Categories

    All

    Tweets by Perspective_PA
    Follow @Perspective_PA
© Perspective Climate Consultancy 2021
+44 (0)20 8806 5176
Company Number 9034546